Trade under Imperfect Competition and the Gravity ... - Gregory Corcos

The Krugman Model. - Assumptions ... We need a new, imperfect competition trade model ..... Distance proxies transportation costs, time as a trade barrier,.
473KB taille 4 téléchargements 327 vues
Trade under Imperfect Competition and the Gravity Equation Guest lecture by Geoffrey Barrows

ECO 434: Economie Internationale Ecole Polytechnique, 2`eme Ann´ee http://gregory.corcos.free.fr/ECO434/ECO434.html

Outline

• Introduction: trade in similar products between similar countries • The Krugman Model - Assumptions - Autarky and open-economy equilibria • Empirical Evidence: the Gravity Equation - Microfoundations - Main lessons

2/37

Introduction

• Ricardo/HOS predict trade in different goods by different

countries: - differences in productivity (Ricardo) or factor endowments (HOS) - specialization in comparative advantage goods • These models do not explain - trade between similar countries - trade in similar goods - the ’gravity equation’ (seen in Chapter 1) • We need a new, imperfect competition trade model - similar countries trade differentiated varieties of the same goods - consumers gain from additional product diversity

3/37

0

Trade Value (billions USD) 2 4

6

World Trade by Region

1970

1980

1990 North−North South−South

2000

2010

North−South South−North

Most of world trade occurs between similar countries. Source: UN ComTrade

4/37

Table: Intra-industry trade (IIT) shares in bilateral trade flows (top 10)

Source: Fontagn´ e, Freudenberg and Gaulier (2006). Intra-Industry Trade is defined as simultaneous trade of narrowly defined goods in both directions between two countries. This Table reports the 10 country pairs with the highest IIT shares.

5/37

The Krugman Model

6/37

Paul Krugman (1953- ) Scale Economies, Product Differentiation and the Pattern of Trade, American Economic Review, 1980

7/37

Overview

• Ingredients: • Countries have identical endowments, technology and preferences. • Economies of scale • Differentiated (imperfectly substitutable) products. • Monopolistic competition: firms have market power on their variety. • Free entry: the number of firms is endogenous • All the neoclassical motives for trade are absent! • Trade occurs because consumers have demand for foreign varieties,

and large trade partners offer more varieties.

8/37

Consumption • One factor: labor (L). National income: wL. • Utility defined over a continuum of varieties Ω:

Z max U = max q(ω)

q(ω)

q(ω)

σ−1 σ

σ  σ−1



Z s.t.



p(ω)q(ω)dω = wL Ω

with σ > 1 the elasticity of substitution between varieties. • Utility maximization yields the demand function:

 q(ω) = with P =

9/37

R Ω

p(ω)1−σ dω

1  1−σ

p(ω) P

−σ

wL P

(1)

10/37

• P is the “ideal price index”: 1 unit of utility costs P units of income. • To see this, plug demand functions into the utility function Z U

=

q(ω)

σ−1 σ



σ σ−1



Z  =



wL σ P P

=



Z p(ω)

1−σ

 dω



σ σ−1

=

p(ω) P

−σ σ−1  σ

wL P

σ ! σ−1

 σ−1 σ



wL P

• P is lower than the simple average of prices p(ω):

P=

R Ω

p(ω)1−σ dω

1  1−σ


1 prices

are lower in the large country: fewer varieties bear shipping costs. Price indices, wages

15/37

Gains From Trade Price Levels (Home is the large country) 1.5 OE Home OE Foreign Aut Home Aut Foreign

1.4

1.3

1.2

1.1

1

0.9

0.8

16/37

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5 τ1−σ

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

Wages

• Substituting for prices, quantities and numbers of firms in the trade

balance equation np X q X = n∗ p X ∗ q X ∗ yields w w∗

 =

P P∗

 1−σ σ

1−σ

=

Lw 1−σ + L∗ (τ w ∗ ) L (τ w )

1−σ

! σ1

+ L∗ w ∗ 1−σ

• When τ = 1 wages are equal in both countries.

 1 → LL∗ 2σ−1 . Thanks to better market access the large country’s firms sell and hire disproportionately more.

• When τ → +∞,

w w∗

• An extended model with mobile workers can explain economic

agglomeration in some countries or regions.

17/37

Gravity Regressions

18/37

From Theory to Gravity Regressions • In the model aggregate exports equal X = np X q X • We predict that exports from i to j equal

 Xij = ni

σ τij wi σ − 1 ϕi Pj

1−σ Rj

or in logs:  ln Xij

=

ln |

σ σ−1 {z

1−σ

constant

wi + ln ni + (1 − σ) ln ϕi {z } } | i−specific

+ ln Pjσ−1 |

+ ln Rj + (1 − σ) ln τij {z } {z } |

j−specific

transport cost

• ’Gravity’ empirical equation

ln Xij = κ + αXi + βMj + γ ln distij + δCij + εij 19/37

Trade between US States and Canadian Provinces

Source: Feenstra & Taylor (2011)

20/37

Gravity Equation Estimates Variable dependante: ln Xij (2) (3) (4) (5) 1.185a

ln Population i

(1) 0.799a

ln GDP/capita i

1.072a

1.272a

a

0.896a

a

0.920a

a

-1.008

-1.511a

1970 No 9,035 0.583

2006 No 16,936 0.631

ln Population j ln GDP/capita j ln Distance

0.723 1.058

Trade Agreement GATT/WTO Common Currency Common Border Common Language Colonial Past Year Country Fixed Effects # Observations R2

21/37

(6)

Gravity Equation Estimates ln Population i

(2) 0.823a

ln GDP/capita i

1.072a

1.110a

1.272a

1.265a

a

a

a

0.900a

a

0.912a

a

-1.199a

-1.619a

ln Population j ln GDP/capita j ln Distance

0.723

a

1.058

a

-1.008

Trade Agreement GATT/WTO

0.740

0.896

a

1.092

0.920 a

(6)

a

-0.838

-1.000

0.917a

0.643a

0.758a

0.493a

-0.011

0.038

a

0.811a

a

a

-1.511

0.306

Common Currency

1.470

1.460

-0.029

0.035

Common Border

0.588a

0.533a

1.152a

0.840a

Common Language

0.559a

0.535a

1.108a

0.909a

a

a

a

0.672

0.889a

2006 No 16,936 0.649

2006 Yes 16,936 0.741

Colonial Past Year Country Fixed Effects # Observations R2

22/37

Dependent variable: ln Xij (3) (4) (5) 1.185a 1.191a

(1) 0.799a

1970 No 9,035 0.583

1.376

1.277

1970 No 9,035 0.607

1970 Yes 9,035 0.710

2006 No 16,936 0.631

.6

.8

Distance Elasticity 1 1.2 1.4

1.6

The Distance Elasticity Over Time

1945

1955

1965

1975

1985

1995

2005

• An elasticity of 1 means that doubling distance reduces trade by half. • Distance proxies transportation costs, time as a trade barrier,

cultural distance and informational frictions. • Increasing spatial concentration of trade over time... 23/37

Other Results

• Trade Agreements - Trade is 40% higher between partners of a trade agreement. • Currency Unions - Trade is twice as high between members of a currency union. • Cultural Links - Trade is higher between countries that share a language or historical links

Note: these are correlations. Stating causality requires further work...

24/37

The Border Effect in the EU Effet Frontière : Flux Intranationaux / Flux Internationaux

30 Lancement du Marché Unique 25 20 15 10 5 0 1975

1980

1985 Année

Source : Head et Mayer (2000) Source: Head & Mayer (2000)

25/37

1990

1995

Limits of the Gravity Equation

• The within-EU border effect remains an empirical puzzle. • ’Zeroes’: - trade flows are zero for over 50% of country pairs, even more when using sector-level trade flows - zeroes require special econometric techniques to estimate the gravity equation - zeroes require an extension of the Krugman model, where there is always some demand for each variety

26/37

Conclusions

• Neoclassical trade models explain trade in different goods between

different countries. • The Krugman trade model explain trade in similar goods between

similar countries. • comparative advantage trade motives are absent • trade occurs because of demand for different varieties of the same

product • product diversity creates gains from trade

• The model is consistent with ’gravity’ regression results: trade flows

are higher between countries that are large, close, share the same language, history, currency or have signed trade agreements.

27/37

Appendix

28/37

How to derive the demand function • Lagrangian: L =

R Ω

q(ω)

σ−1 σ





σ σ−1

−µ

R Ω

 p(ω)q(ω)dω − wL

• First order conditions: −1 ∂L = q(ω) σ ∂q(ω) −1 σ

Z q(ω)

σ−1 σ

 dω

1 σ−1

− µp(ω) = 0



1



q(ω)



q(ω) = Uµ−σ p(ω)−σ

U σ = µp(ω)

R p(ω)q(ω)dω = Uµ−σ Ω p(ω)1−σ dω  1 R • Define the price index P = Ω p(ω)1−σ dω 1−σ . The budget constraint is rewritten as wL = Uµ−σ P 1−σ

• Budget constraint: wL =

R



• Note that wL = PU. P is the monetary value of one unit of utility.

29/37

• From the budget constraint wL = Uµ−σ P 1−σ and the f.o.c. q(ω) = Uµ−σ p(ω)−σ , one obtains the demand function:  −σ p(ω) wL q(ω) = P P • Demand for variety ω increases with overall purchasing power wL/P, and decreases with the relative price of variety ω. • σ is equal to • the price elasticity: a 1% rise in p(ω) reduces demand by σ% • the elasticity of substitution: since

q(ω) q(ω 0 )

=



p(ω) p(ω 0 )

−σ

, increasing the

relative price of the ω variety by 1% reduces the relative demand for this variety by σ% Back to main text

30/37

How to derive the optimal price • Start from the firm’s profit function:   q(ω) π(ω) = p(ω)q(ω) − w f + ϕ • Maximize with respect to price given demand and price index P ⇒ First order condition:   ∂π(ω) w = P σ−1 wL (1 − σ)p −σ + σp −σ−1 = 0 ∂p(ω) ϕ Or after rearranging: p=

σ σ−1 | {z }

w ϕ |{z}

Mark−up Marginal cost Back to main text

31/37

Price indices in a two-country world economy • The price index is now written as: 

 X

P=

ω∈H

1−σ

p(ω)

+

X



(τ p (ω))

1 1−σ

1−σ 

ω∈F

• In the symmetric equilibrium, p(ω) = p, ∀ω ∈ H and p ∗ (ω) = p ∗ , ∀ω ∈ F ⇒ and

P = np 1−σ + n∗ (τ p ∗ )1−σ



1 1−σ

P ∗ = n(τ p)1−σ + n∗ p ∗ 1−σ



1 1−σ

• Absent transportation costs (τ = 1), with identical countries, the two indices are 1

equal: P = P ∗ = (2n) 1−σ p. Both countries have access to the same varieties in the same conditions. 1

• Both indices are lower than those in autarky, which are: P = n 1−σ p and P∗ = n

1 1−σ

p∗

• At given wages, opening up the economy has a positive impact on welfare (U = wL/P). This comes from consumers’ preference for diversity Back to main text 32/37

Wages • We have expressed optimal prices p(ω) and P as functions of nominal income wL.

• L is exogenous but w is endogenous • The wage is determined by the goods market equilibrium equation. Due to Walras’P law, it is equivalent to rely on (i) the domestic P market (wL = ω wl(ω)); (ii) the foreign market (w ∗ L∗ = ω w ∗ l ∗ (ω)); (iii) the trade balance (X = X ∗ )

• We use the trade balance: λ × L × L∗ × ⇒ with ⇒

33/37

 τ w 1−σ P∗

× w ∗ = λ × L × L∗ ×

  1−σ σ w P = ∗ ∗ w P   P np 1−σ + n∗ (τ p ∗ )1−σ = ∗ P n(τ p)1−σ + n∗ p ∗ 1−σ  1/σ w Lw 1−σ + L∗ (τ w ∗ )1−σ = w∗ L(τ w )1−σ + L∗ w ∗ 1−σ



τw∗ P

1−σ ×w

Relative imports: M n∗ = M∗ n



τ p ∗ /P τ p/P ∗

1−σ

w wL = ∗ ∗ ∗ w L w

• Starting from the symetric equilibrium:

L L∗



=

w ∗ /P w /P ∗

w w∗

=

1−σ

M M∗

• An increase in L/L∗ increases the relative number of firms in H

which reduces P/P ∗ . This makes foreign goods relatively more expansive → ↓ M/M ∗ • For trade to be balanced, needs to be compensated by an increase in

the relative wage w /w ∗ → ↑ M/M ∗ through an income effect (↑ aggregate demand) and a substitution effect (↓ relative competitiveness of domestically produced varieties) ⇒ Wages are relatively high in large countries

34/37

Back to section 1

Wages (2) Relative wage in the large country, as a function of the “freeness” of trade τ 1−σ Relative Wage in the Large Country 1.09 1.08 1.07 1.06 1.05 1.04 1.03 1.02 1.01 1

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5 τ1−σ

35/37

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1

Welfare gains

1

1

• Autarky: P = pn 1−σ and P ∗ = p ∗ n∗ 1−σ • Open economy: P = p 1−σ n + (τ p ∗ )1−σ n∗







P = p

∗ 1−σ ∗

1−σ

n + (τ p)

n

1  1−σ

and

1  1−σ

• Without transportation costs: 1

1

P = P ∗ = (2np 1−σ ) 1−σ < (np 1−σ ) 1−σ since σ > 1 ⇒ Opening up the economy yields a welfare gain deriving from more diversity. • In Krugman (1979), trade has a pro-competitive effect too (fall in p

due to a rise in σ).

36/37

Prices as a function of the “freeness” of trade τ 1−σ Price Levels (Home is the large country) 1.5 OE Home OE Foreign Aut Home Aut Foreign

1.4

1.3

1.2

1.1

1

0.9

0.8

0

0.1

0.2

0.3

0.4

0.5 τ1−σ

37/37

0.6

0.7

0.8

0.9

1